Classroom The Office About Contested Knowledges The Wilderness Exploration The Issues Notices Tutorial Discussions
Glossary
Bibliography
Student Web Pages

Issues

Economics Education Fire Gender History Land Language Law Medicine Nature

 

Link to Economics discussion page
Economics
Introduction

Trade and exchange of goods is a fundamental part of any cultural group's activity. People exchange labour for food, material wealth, favours and money. People produce things that others want and are able to exchange those objects or services for objects and services they want. Some form of economics is therefore a component of all cultural activity.

The economics of the western world seems, however, to be the dominant economic paradigm and is increasingly becoming the model by which all other forms of economic activity are measured.

Think about:


  • How did this happen?

  • What made western economics the yardstick?

Other systems exist, however, they are not legitimised, they are considered inferior, illegal or non-existent in the contestation for power and access to resources controlled by economic activity.

What is at stake?

The legitimisation of one economic system over others demonstrates the importance of this contestation as one that is carried out over key epistemological issues. Your economics: what you consider to be legitimate economic activity; is constrained by your ontology. Who you are and what you consider to be true and right determines your approach to economic activity. How you are placed within that economic system determines how you deal, interact and relate to other people.

On a broader scale, the use of one economic system instead of another or one overlain across others that already exists, demonstrates to important hegemonic relationships between the different groups of people involved and identifies the relations of power that exist.

Think about:


  • How are power and economics related?

  • What epistemological questions are raised by the promotion of one economic system over another?

What is the status quo?

Economists rarely agree on definitions of economics. It could be said that 'Economics is what economists do' but it still begs the question, 'What is an economist?' The Penguin Dictionary provides a clue with the following definition

Economics is a science concerned with those aspects of social behaviour, and those institutions, which are involved in the use of scarce resources in the satisfaction of human wants. (p147)

Western economics has increasingly been built around core ideas of self-interested individualism and contractual exchange to satisfy wants. This sees the central character as the autonomous agent who trades with other agents in order to maximise a utility or profit function. Both micro-economists and macroeconomists explain the economy in ways that are consistent with this core. Modern mainstream economics is a way of explaining behaviour rather than trying to collate and classify information or 'facts'.

What are the alternatives?

If you have a dominant form of economic activity being carried out, now almost in a global sense, the question is:


  • Which voices have been included and represented in this construction of economics?

Proscribing what counts as economics

By proscribing what counts as economics, this silences serious challenges to the primacy of the core ideas of self-interested individualism and contractual exchange. It could be argued that such theories reflect a distinctly masculine and western perspective on self-hood and individual agency and how we see the economy.

Economics with higher status

A popular view is that the explanation of the core ideas has high status because of their obvious logic or superior power of thinking. The conceptual structure of modern economics appears natural and obvious to the practitioners in the field. It is easy to forget that the knowledge might be partial, that the economic models might be highlighting certain aspects while suppressing others. We forget that models that economists love to use are just that - 'models' - which may help us to understand aspects of the world, which might be 'true' in the model, but are not literally 'true' in the world. They are all based on assumptions.

Innocent actions

Another problem is that economists tend to view the simplifications and assumptions in the models as relatively innocent. Decisions are made as to count some phenomena as being more important than others thus underpinning the value judgements that are disguised in making such decisions.

Strassman (1993) uses a number of what she calls 'stories' to illustrate the problems.

The story of the marketplace of ideas [she argues] is a classical example of economic imperialism - the application of economic explanation to domains viewed as being outside the traditional purview of economics, in this case the philosophy of science and anthropology. In the marketplace of ideas the "best" ideas bubble to the top, rising in value according to merit. Ideas are exchanged as in a marketplace, their worth ascertained in a competitive process of bidding and exchange. This story implies that the dominant economic theories are valued because of their worthiness, with no role for cultural values or institutional configurations (p56).

Questions remain:


  • Who are the judges of the "best" ideas?

    • Who selects the 'worthy' scholars to become the judges?

    • What happens (using the marketplace metaphor) if there is imperfect competition in the marketplace of ideas?

      • Are the dominant practitioners simply protecting their intellectual marketplace with exclusionary practices?

Dissenters are easily relegated to the less important journals or are simply not published. Women and culturally different groups may well disagree with the standard models of economics but only those who agree are going to be admitted into the ranks.

The benevolent patriarch

Another economic story of hers is that of the 'benevolent' patriarch. In this story the patriarch makes economic choices in the best interests of all members of the family. The patriarch may take individual family members' preferences into account but he still makes the decisions for their well being (which may or may not be linked to individual well being). When the patriarch becomes the coloniser the effects can be similar.

Colonisation of economics

When the colonisers arrived on the lands of Indigenous peoples around the world, they were often completely blind to the economic systems at work in the traditional societies. The disruption of existing economic systems often caused social and cultural breakdown, which was often interpreted by the colonisers as simply a sign of depravity of primitive cultures and certainly not to any faulty mainstream economic thinking - rather a case of the 'primitives' not knowing their own best interests. Again this story is useful in that it shows that often economists fail to recognise the limited scope of application of models and concepts, a failure that can lead to inadequate or inappropriate policies and practices.

What happens when different knowledges speak to each other?

With other systems and other cultures all practising economic activity, the dominance of one system over a range of others may make some sense, but in other senses, the local economies reflect local conditions and needs. The utility of the western system condenses to colonial oppression and political domination. By speaking to each other, systems of economics provide the opportunity to develop in ways that prevent the benefits of local and regional economies to retained and the location of power more legitimately remaining broad rather than concentrated within the few who control western economic systems.

Think about:


  • In what ways does a global western economy prevent local sharing of resources and power?

  • Is it possible to develop legitimate local economies?

  • How would the resources and power be equitably shared across a range of different groups?

Resources

There are a wide range of resources that you can use to develop your understanding of economics and alternative economic philosophies.

Reading 5.3

Escobar, A., 1995 'Economics as Culture' in Encountering Development: The Making and the Unmaking of the Third World, Princeton University Press, New Jersey, pp 58 - 63.

Other References

Capra, F., 1982 'The Impasse of Economics' in The Turning Point: Science, Society and the Rising Culture, Bantam, New York, pp 188 - 233.

Strassman, D., 1993 'Not a free market' in Beyond Economic Man: Feminist Theory and Economics, eds. M. A. Ferber and J.A. Nelson, The University of Chicago Press, Chicago and London.

Strassman, D. & Polanyi, L., 1992 'Shifting the Paradigm: Value in Feminist Critiques of Economics', paper presented in the First Annual Conference of the International Association for Feminist Economics, July 1992, Washington, D.C.

 
Top of Page
Charles Darwin University
   

Charles Darwin University
Site Disclaimer

 

Last Modified:12 Feb 2016
Modified by:greg.williams@cdu.edu.au